• If you are having problems logging in please use the Contact Us in the lower right hand corner of the forum page for assistance.

Oil, & The Sherman Act Gone Wrong

Help Support Ranchers.net:

Mike

Well-known member
Joined
Feb 10, 2005
Messages
28,480
Reaction score
2
Location
Montgomery, Al
Sunday marks the 100th anniversary of the Supreme Court ruling that found Standard Oil guilty of violating the Sherman Antitrust Act. As punishment, the world's largest and most successful oil company was broken into 34 pieces.

Ever since, Standard Oil has served as the textbook example of why we need antitrust law. The Court's decision affirmed a popular account of Standard Oil's success, first made famous by journalists Henry Demarest Lloyd and Ida Tarbell. In the absence of antitrust laws, the story goes, Standard attained a 90% share of the oil-refining market through unfair and destructive practices such as preferential railroad rebates and "predatory pricing"; Standard then leveraged its unfair advantages to eliminate competition, control the market, and dictate prices. In Lloyd's words, Standard was "making us pay what it pleases for kerosene."

Was it? In 1865, when Rockefeller's market share was still minuscule, a gallon of kerosene cost 58 cents. In 1870, Standard's market share was 4%, and a gallon cost 26 cents. By 1880, when Standard's market share had skyrocketed to 90%, a gallon cost only 9 cents — and a decade later, with Standard's market share still at 90%, the price was 7 cents. These data point to the real cause of Standard Oil's success — its ability to charge the lowest prices by producing kerosene with unparalleled efficiency.

John D. Rockefeller had a rare business mind. He was at once a visionary, foreseeing a world in which his kerosene illuminated millions of homes, and an accountant obsessed with day-to-day penny-pinching. Upon buying his first refinery in 1863 at the age of 23, Rockefeller started optimizing every part of his business, from his storage facilities to his refining methods to the number of non-kerosene-refined products (waxes, lubricants, etc.) that could be squeezed from every barrel.

In pursuit of efficiency, Rockefeller employed then-rare business strategies such as vertical integration and economies of scale. For example, by purchasing his own forest and producing his own barrels, Rockefeller lowered per-barrel costs from $3 to $1 while increasing reliability and quality. To transport oil, Rockefeller obtained large rebates from railroads, not through corrupt conspiracies (the typical explanation) but by dramatically lowering the railroads' costs. Where others offered railroads unreliable, highly variable traffic, Rockefeller offered guaranteed daily fleets of Standard-owned tank cars, loaded and unloaded by Standard-provided facilities, for straight-line trips from Cleveland to New York. The Lake Shore Railroad's James Devereux testified that Standard Oil lowered transport costs from $900,000 to $300,000 a trip.

Rockefeller was simply a man ahead of his time — and his competition. In the 1860s, refining was a comfortable business; high demand for kerosene plus low supply of refining capacity made for hefty profit margins, even for outfits with mediocre efficiency. Rockefeller, foreseeing that refining capacity would grow to meet demand, was prepared for much lower prices; others weren't. By 1871, refining capacity exceeded oil production, and three-quarters of the industry was losing money.

Rockefeller saw an opportunity to buy out competitors and put their talent and assets to more efficient use. Rockefeller would typically show his books to a prospect, wait for him to be "thunderstruck" (as one observer put it) by Standard's efficiency, and then make a reasonable offer. If a target resisted, Rockefeller would win over their customers by charging a low price that was profitable for Standard but extremely unprofitable for others.


Read more: http://dailycaller.com/2011/05/13/vindicating-standard-oil-100-years-later/#ixzz1MWIZCQLW
 
Mike said:
Sunday marks the 100th anniversary of the Supreme Court ruling that found Standard Oil guilty of violating the Sherman Antitrust Act. As punishment, the world's largest and most successful oil company was broken into 34 pieces.

Ever since, Standard Oil has served as the textbook example of why we need antitrust law. The Court's decision affirmed a popular account of Standard Oil's success, first made famous by journalists Henry Demarest Lloyd and Ida Tarbell. In the absence of antitrust laws, the story goes, Standard attained a 90% share of the oil-refining market through unfair and destructive practices such as preferential railroad rebates and "predatory pricing"; Standard then leveraged its unfair advantages to eliminate competition, control the market, and dictate prices. In Lloyd's words, Standard was "making us pay what it pleases for kerosene."

Was it? In 1865, when Rockefeller's market share was still minuscule, a gallon of kerosene cost 58 cents. In 1870, Standard's market share was 4%, and a gallon cost 26 cents. By 1880, when Standard's market share had skyrocketed to 90%, a gallon cost only 9 cents — and a decade later, with Standard's market share still at 90%, the price was 7 cents. These data point to the real cause of Standard Oil's success — its ability to charge the lowest prices by producing kerosene with unparalleled efficiency.

John D. Rockefeller had a rare business mind. He was at once a visionary, foreseeing a world in which his kerosene illuminated millions of homes, and an accountant obsessed with day-to-day penny-pinching. Upon buying his first refinery in 1863 at the age of 23, Rockefeller started optimizing every part of his business, from his storage facilities to his refining methods to the number of non-kerosene-refined products (waxes, lubricants, etc.) that could be squeezed from every barrel.

In pursuit of efficiency, Rockefeller employed then-rare business strategies such as vertical integration and economies of scale. For example, by purchasing his own forest and producing his own barrels, Rockefeller lowered per-barrel costs from $3 to $1 while increasing reliability and quality. To transport oil, Rockefeller obtained large rebates from railroads, not through corrupt conspiracies (the typical explanation) but by dramatically lowering the railroads' costs. Where others offered railroads unreliable, highly variable traffic, Rockefeller offered guaranteed daily fleets of Standard-owned tank cars, loaded and unloaded by Standard-provided facilities, for straight-line trips from Cleveland to New York. The Lake Shore Railroad's James Devereux testified that Standard Oil lowered transport costs from $900,000 to $300,000 a trip.

Rockefeller was simply a man ahead of his time — and his competition. In the 1860s, refining was a comfortable business; high demand for kerosene plus low supply of refining capacity made for hefty profit margins, even for outfits with mediocre efficiency. Rockefeller, foreseeing that refining capacity would grow to meet demand, was prepared for much lower prices; others weren't. By 1871, refining capacity exceeded oil production, and three-quarters of the industry was losing money.

Rockefeller saw an opportunity to buy out competitors and put their talent and assets to more efficient use. Rockefeller would typically show his books to a prospect, wait for him to be "thunderstruck" (as one observer put it) by Standard's efficiency, and then make a reasonable offer. If a target resisted, Rockefeller would win over their customers by charging a low price that was profitable for Standard but extremely unprofitable for others.


Read more: http://dailycaller.com/2011/05/13/vindicating-standard-oil-100-years-later/#ixzz1MWIZCQLW

The continuation of finding oil brought the price down for consumers. Whale oil (which was diminishing hence the high prices) was the main constituent of a new industrial economy then mineral oil. In the mean time, Standard Oil continually used its market muscle to capture that part of the economy for themselves and every new find of oil was weaseled out of the finders in various ways, increased rail road rates for getting the oil to market etc.

Monopolies can be the cheapest at getting a product out because they usually decrease the number of profit centers and consolidate them. In the mean time, they use their market power to capture all the business opportunities. How would you like it if a cattle baron did that to your business--- paying you less for your cattle or spreading a rumor to get you to sell for less etc.?

Monopolies usually use their market power to extract monopoly profits where they can. They don't do it everywhere because in some places they are playing the competition game to run out competitors.

There is a real good book on these economic issues and how a few very wealthy men, The Robber Barons, captured much of the nation's transportation, financial and other industries for themselves. They became super wealthy at the expense of society and free markets working to produce an economy that works for everyone in it, not just a select few Robber Barons.

The anti trust laws were born out of these abuses and what it did to the economy. It was the lessons learned of following the richest in their attempt to capture the economy for themselves through the lowest price game. It is too bad we have to revisit those same lessons even today.

Tex
 

Latest posts

Top